Saturday, April 14, 2018

PART 4 : HISTORY OF THE GREAT AMERICAN FORTUNES;THE GROWTH OF THE ASTOR FORTUNE

HISTORY OF THE GREAT 
AMERICAN FORTUNES
BY GUSTAVUS MYERS
CHAPTER III
THE GROWTH OF 
THE ASTOR FORTUNE
Image result for images of John Jacob Astor,



While at the outposts, and in the depths, of the Western wilderness an armed host was working and cheating for Astor, and, in turn, being cheated by their employer ;  while, for Astor’s gain, they were violating all laws, debauching, demoralizing and beggaring entire tribes of Indians, slaying and often being themselves slain in retaliation, what was the beneficiary of this orgy of crime and bloodshed doing in New York ?

For a long time he lived at No. 223 Broadway in a large double house, flanked by an imposing open piazza supported by pillars and arches.  In this house he combined the style of the ascending capitalist with the fittings and trappings of the tradesman.  It was at once residence, office and salesroom.  On the ground floor was his store, loaded with furs ;  and here one of his sons and his chief heir, William B. could be seen, as a lad, assiduously beating the furs to keep out moths.  Astor’s disposition was phlegmatic and his habits were extremely simple and methodical.  He had dinner regularly at three o’clock, after which he would limit himself to three games of checkers and a glass of beer.  Most of his long day was taken up with close attention to his many business interests of which no detail escaped him.  However execrated he might be in the Indian territories far in the West, he assumed, and somewhat succeeded in being credited with, the character of a patriotic, respectable and astute man of business in New York.

ASTOR SUPERIOR TO LAW.

During (taking a wide survey) the same series of years that he was directing gross violations of explicit laws in the fur-producing regions — laws upon the observance of which depended the very safety of the life of men, women and children, white and red, and which laws were vested with an importance corresponding with the baneful and bloody results of their infraction — Astor was turning other laws to his distinct advantage in the East.  Pillaging in the West the rightful and legal domain, and the possessions, of a dozen Indian tribes, he, in the East, was causing public money to be turned over to his private treasury and using it as personal capital in his shipping enterprises.

As applied to the business and landowning class, law was notoriously a flexible, convenient, and highly adaptable function.  By either the tacit permission or connivance of Government, this class was virtually, in most instances, its own law-regulator.  It could consistently, and without being seriously interfered with, violate such laws as suited its interests, while calling for the enactment or enforcement of other laws which favored its designs and enhanced its profits.  We see Astor ruthlessly brushing aside, like so many annoying encumbrances, even those very laws which were commonly held indispensable to a modicum of fair treatment of the Indians and to the preservation of human life.  These laws happened to conflict with the amassing of profits ;  and always in a civilization ruled by the trading class, laws which do this are either unceremoniously trampled upon, evaded or repealed.

For ail the long-continued violations of law in the West, and for the horrors which resulted from his exploitation of the Indians, was Astor ever prosecuted ?  To repeat, no ;  nor was he disturbed even by such a triviality as a formal summons.  Yet, to realize the full enormity of acts for which he was responsible, and the complete measure of which that he enjoyed, it is necessary to recall that at the time the Government had already begun to assume the role of looking upon the Indians as its wards, and thus of theoretically extending to them the shield of its especial protection.  If Government allowed a people whom it pleased to signify as its wards to be debauched, plundered and slain, what kind of treatment could be expected for the working class as to which there was not even the fiction of Government concern, not to mention wardship ?

LAW BREAKERS AND LAW MAKERS.

But when it came to laws which, in the remotest degree, could be used or manipulated to swell profits or to buttress property, Astor and his class were untiring and vociferous in demanding their strict enforcement.  Successfully ignoring or circumventing laws objectionable to them, they, at the same time, insisted upon the passage and exact construction and severe enforcement of laws which were adjusted to their interests.  Law breakers, on the one hand, they were law makers on the other.  They caused to be put in statute, and intensified by judicial precedent, the most rigorous laws in favor of property rights.  They, virtually had the extraordinary power of choosing what laws they should observe and what they should not.  This choice was invariably at the expense of the working class.  Law, that much-sanctified product, was really law only when applied to the property less.  It confronted the poor at every step, was executed with summary promptitude and filled the prisons with them.  Poverty had no choice in saying what laws it should obey and what it should not.  It, perforce, had to obey or go to prison ;  either one or the other, for the laws were expressly drafted to bear heavily upon it.

It is illustrative, in the highest degree, of the character of Government ruled by commercial interests, that Astor was allowed to pillage and plunder, cheat, rob and (by proxy) slaughter in the West, while, in the East, that same Government extended to him, as well as to other shippers, the free use of money which came from the taxation of the whole people — a taxation always weighted upon the shoulders of the worker.  In turn, this favored class, either consciously or unconsciously, voluntarily or involuntarily, cheated the Government of nearly half of the sums advanced.  From the foundation of the Government up to 1837, there were nine distinct commercial crises which brought about terrible hardships to the wage workers.  Did the Government step in and assist them ?  At no time.  But during all those years the Government was busy in letting the shippers dig into the public funds and in being extremely generous to them when they failed to pay up.  From 1789 to 1823 the Government lost more than $250,000,000 in duties,1 all of which sum represented what the shippers owed and did not, or could not, pay.  And no criminal proceedings were brought against any of these defaulters.

This, however, was not all that the Government did for the favored, pampered class that it represented.  Laws were severe against labor-union strikes, which were frequently judicially adjudged conspiracies.  Theoretically, law inhibited monopoly, but monopolies existed, because law ceases to be effective law when it is not enforced ;  and the propertied interests took care that it was not enforced.  Their own class was powerful in every branch of Government.  Furthermore, they had the money to buy political subservience and legal dexterity.  The $35,000 that Astor paid to Cass, the very official who, as Secretary of War, had jurisdiction over the Indian tribes and over the Indian trade, and the sums that Astor paid to Benton, were, it may well be supposed, only the merest parts of the total sums that he disbursed to officials and politicians, high and low.

ASTOR’S MONOPOLIES.

Astor profited richly from his monopolies.  His monopoly of furs in the West was made a basis for the creation of other monopolies.  China was a voracious and highly profitable market for furs.  In exchange for the cargoes of these that he sent there, his ships would be loaded with teas and silks.  These products he sold at exorbitant prices in New York.  His profits from a single voyage sometimes reached $70,000 ;  the average profits from a single voyage were $30,000.  During the War of 1812-15 tea rose to double its usual price.  Astor was invariably lucky in that his ships escaped capture.  At one period he was about the only merchant who had a cargo of tea in the market.  He exacted, and was allowed to exact, his own price.

Meanwhile, Astor was setting about making himself the richest and largest landowner in the country.  His were not the most extensive land possessions in point of extent but in regard to value.  He aimed at being a great city, not a great rural, landlord.  It was estimated that his trade in furs and associated commerce brought him a clear annual revenue of about two million dollars.  This estimate was palpably inadequate.  Not only did he reap enormous profits from the fur trade, but also from banking privileges in which he was a conspicuous factor.

It was on one of his visits to London, so the recital goes, that he first became possessed of the idea of founding an extraordinarily rich landed family.  He admired, it is told, the great landed estates of the British nobility, and observed the prejudice against the caste of the trader and the corresponding exalted position of the landowner.  Whether this story is true or not, it is evident that he was impressed with the increasing power and the stability of a fortune founded upon land, and how it radiated a certain splendid prestige.  The very definition of the word landlord — lord of the soil — signified the awe-compelling and authoritative position of him who owned land — a definition heightened and enforced in a thousand ways by the laws.

The speculative and solid possibilities of New York City real estate held out dazzling opportunities gratifying his acquisitiveness for wealth and power — the wealth that fed his avarice, and the power flowing from the dominion of riches.

ASTOR NOT AN EXCEPTION.

It may here be observed that Astor’s methods in trade or in acquiring of land need not be indiscriminately condemned as an exclusive mania.  Nor should they be held up to the curiosity of posterity as a singular and pernicious exhibition, detached from his time and generation, and independent of them.  Again and again the facts disclose that men such as he were merely the representative crests of prevailing commercial and political life.  Substantially the whole propertied class obtained its wealth by methods which, if not the same, had a strong relationship.  His methods differed nowise from those of many cotton planters of the South who stole, on a monstrous scale,2 Government land and then with the wealth derived from their thefts, bought negro slaves, set themselves up in the glamour of a patriarchal aristocracy and paraded a florid display of chivalry and honor.  And it was this same grandiose class that plundered Whitney of the fruits of his invention of the cotton-gin and shamelessly defrauded him.3

Far more flagrant, however, were the means by which other Southern plantation owners and business firms secured landed estates in Alabama, Georgia and in other States.  Their methods in expropriating the reservations of such Indian tribes as the Creeks and Chickasaws were not less fraudulent than those that Astor used elsewhere.  They too, those fine Southern aristocrats, debauched Indian tribes with whisky, and after swindling them of their land, caused the Government to remove them westward.  The frauds were so extensive, and the circumstances so repellent, that President Andrew Jackson, in 1833, ordered an investigation.  From the records of this investigation,— four hundred and twenty-five solid pages of official correspondence — more than enough details can be obtained.4

WHERE WAS FRAUD ABSENT ?

In Wisconsin the most valuable Government lands, containing rich deposits of lead and other mineral ore, were being boldly appropriated by force and fraud.  The House Committee on Public Lands reported on December 18, 1840, that with the connivance of local land agents, these lands, since 1835, had been sold at private sale before they were even subject to public entry.5  “ In consequence of which,” the Committee stated, “ many tracts of land known to be rich and valuable mineral lands for many years, and known to be such at the time of the entry, have been entered by evil-minded persons, who have falsely made, or procured others to make, the oath required by the land offices.  Honest men have been excluded from the purchase of these lands, while the dishonest and unscrupulous have been permitted to enter them by means of false oath and fraud.”6

These are but the merest glimpses of the widespread frauds in seizing land, whether agricultural, timber or mineral.  What of the mercantile importers, the same class that the Government so greatly favored in allowing it long periods in which to pay its customs duties ?  It was defrauding the Government on the very importations on which it was extended long-time credit for customs payments.  The few official reports available clearly indicate this.  Great frauds were continuously going on in the importations of lead.7  Large quantities of sugar were imported in the guise of molasses which, it was discovered, after being boiled a few minutes, would produce an almost equal weight in brown sugar.8  Doubtless similar frauds were being committed in other lines of importations.  Between the methods of these divisions of the capitalist class, and those of Astor, no basic difference can be discerned.

Neither was there any essential difference between Astor’s methods and those of the manufacturing capitalists of the North who remorselessly robbed Charles Goodyear of the benefits of his discovery of vulcanized rubber and who drove him, after protracted litigation, into insolvency, and caused him to die loaded down with worries and debts, a broken-down man, at the age of 60.9  As for that pretentious body of gentry who professed to spread enlightenment and who set themselves high and solemnly on a pinnacle as dispensers of knowledge and molders of public opinion — the book, periodical and newspaper publishers — their methods at bottom were as fraudulent as any that Astor ever used.  They mercilessly robbed and knew it, while making the most hypocritical professions of lofty motives.  Buried deep in the dusty archives of the United States Senate is a petition whereon appear the signatures of Moore, Carlyle, the two Disraelis, Milman, Hallam, Southey, Thomas Campbell, Sir Charles Lyell, Bulwer Lytton, Samuel Rogers, Maria Edgeworth, Harriet Martineau and other British literary luminaries, great or small.  In this petition these authors, some of them representing the highest and finest in literary, philosophical, historical, and scientific thought and expression, implore Congress to afford them protection against the indiscriminate theft of their works by American booksellers.  Their works, they set forth, are not only appropriated without their consent but even contrary to their expressed desire.  And there is no redress.  Their productions are mutilated and altered, yet their names are retained.  They instance the pathetic case of Sir Walter Scott.  His works have been published and sold from Maine to the Gulf of Mexico, yet not a cent has he received.  “An equitable remuneration,” they set forth, “ might have saved his life, and would, at least have relieved his closing years from the burdens of debts and destructive toils.”10

How fares this petition read in the United States Senate on February 2, 1837 ?  The booksellers, magazine, periodical and newspaper publishers have before succeeded in defeating one copyright bill.  They now bestir themselves again ;  the United States Senate consigns the petition to the archives ;  and the piracy goes on as industriously as ever.

LEGALIZED PIRACY IN 
ALL BRANCHES OF TRADE.

What else could be expected from a Congress which represented the commercial and land-holding classes ?  No prodding was needed to cause it to give the fullest protection to possessions in commerce, land and negro slaves ;  these were concrete property.  But thought was not capitalized ;  it was not a manufactured product like iron or soap.  Nothing can express the pitying contempt or the lofty air of patronizing with which the dominant commercial classes looked down upon the writer, the painter, the musician, the philosopher or the sculptor.  Regarding these “ sentimentalists ” as easy, legitimate and defenseless objects of prey, and as incidental and impractical hangers-on in a world where trade was all in all, the commercial classes at all times affected a certain air of encouragement of the fine arts, which encouragement, however, never attempted to put a stop to piracy of publication or reproduction.  How sordidly commercial that era was, to what extremes its standards went, and how some of the basest forms of theft were carried on and practically legalized, may be seen by the fate of Peter Cardelli’s petition to Congress.  Cardelli was a Roman sculptor, residing in the United States for a time.  He prays Congress in 1820 to pass an act protecting him from commercial pirates who make casts and copies of his work and who profit at his expense.  The Senate Committee on judiciary, to whom the petition is referred, rejects the plea.  On what ground ?  Because he “has not discovered any new invention on which he can claim the right.”11  Could stupidity go further ?

All of the confluent facts of the time show conclusively that every stratum of commercial society was permeated with fraud, and that this fraud was accepted generally as a routine fixture of the business of gathering property or profits.  Astor, therefore, was not an isolated phenomenon, but a typically successful representative of his time and of the methods and standards of the trading class of that time.

Whatever in the line of business yielded profits, that act, whether cheating, robbing or slaughtering, was justified by some sophistry or other.  Astor did not debauch, spoliation, and incite slaughter because he took pleasure in doing them.  Perhaps — to extend charitable judgment — he would have preferred to avoid them.  But they were all part of the formulated necessities of business which largely decreed that the exercise of humane and ethical considerations was incompatible with the zealous pursuit of wealth.

In the wilderness of the West, Astor, operating through his agents, could debauch, rob and slay Indians with impunity.  As he was virtually the governing body there, without fear of being hindered, he thus could act in the most high-handed, arbitrary and forcible ways.  In the East, however, where law, or the forms of law, prevailed, he had to have recourse to methods which bore no open trace of the brutal and sanguinary.  He had to become the insidious and devious schemer, acting through sharp lawyers instead of by an armed force.  Hence in his Eastern operations he made deception a science and used every instrument of cunning at his command.  The result was precisely the same as in the West, except that the consequences were not so overt, and the perpetration could not be so easily distinguished.  In the West, death marched step by step with Astor’s accumulating fortune ;  so did it in the East, but it was not open and bloody as in the fur country.  The mortality thus accompanying Astor’s progress in New York was of that slow and indefinite, but more lingering and agonizing kind ensuing from want, destitution, disease and starvation.

Astor’s supreme craft was at no time better shown than by the means by which he acquired possession of an immense estate in Putnam County, New York.  During the Revolution, a tract consisting of 51,012 acres held by Roger Morris and Mary his wife, Tories, had been confiscated by New York State.  This land, it is worth recalling, was part of the estate of Adolphus Phillips, the son of Frederick who, as has been set forth, financed and protected the pirate Captain Samuel Burgess in his buccaneer expeditions, and whose share of the Burgess’ booty was extremely large.12  Mary Morris was a descendant of Adolph Phillips and came into that part of the property by inheritance.  The Morris estate comprised nearly one-third of Putnam County.  After confiscation, the State sold the area in parts to various farmers.  By 1809 seven hundred families were settled on the property, and not a shadow of a doubt had ever been cast on their title.  They had long regarded it as secure, especially as it was guaranteed by the State.

A NOTED LAND TRANSACTION.

In 1809 a browsing lawyer informed Astor that those seven hundred families had no legal title whatever ;  that the State had had no legal right to confiscate the Morris property, inasmuch as the Morris's held a life lease only, and no State could ever confiscate a life lease.  The property, Astor was informed, was really owned by the children of the Morris couple, to whom it was to revert after the lease of their parents was extinguished.  Legally, he was told, they were as much the owners as ever.  Astor satisfied himself that this point would hold in the courts.  Then he assiduously hunted up the heirs, and by a series of strategic maneuvers worthy of the pen of a Balzac, succeeded in buying their claim for $100,000.

In the thirty-three years which had elapsed since confiscation, the land had been greatly improved.  Suddenly came a notification to these unsuspecting farmers that not they, but Astor, owned the land.  All the improvements that they had made, all the accumulated standing products of the thirty-three years’ labor of the occupants, he claimed as his, by virtue of the fact that, in law, they were trespassers.  Dumbfounded, they called upon him to prove his claim.  Whereupon his lawyers, men saturated with the terminology and intricacies of legal lore, came forward and gravely explained that the law said so and so and was such and such and that the law was incontestable in support of Astor’s claim.  The hard-working farmers listened with mystification and consternation.  They could not make out how land which they or their fathers had paid for, and which they had tilled and improved, could belong to an absentee who had never turned a spade on it, had never seen it, all simply because he had the advantage of a legal technicality and a document emblazoned with a seal or two.

THE PUBLIC UPROAR 
OVER ASTOR’S CLAIM.

They appealed to the Legislature.  This body, influenced by the public uproar over the transaction, refused to recognize Astor’s title.  The whole State was aroused to a pitch of indignation.  Astor’s claim was generally regarded as an audacious piece of injustice and robbery.  He contended that he was not subject to the provision of the statute directing sales of confiscated estates which provided that tenants could not be dispossessed without being paid for improvements.  In fine, he claimed the right to evict the entire seven hundred families without being under the legal or moral necessity of paying them a single cent for their improvements.  In the state of public temper, the officials of the State of New York decided to fight his claim.  Astor offered to sell his claim to the State for $667,000.  But such was the public outburst at the effrontery of a man who had bought what was virtually an extinct claim for $100,000, and then attempting to hold up the State for more than six times that sum, that the Legislature dared not consent.

The contention went to the courts and there dragged along for many years.  Astor, however, won his point ;  it was decided that he had a valid title.  Finally in 1827 the Legislature allowed itself 13 to compromise, although public opinion was as bitter as ever.  The State gave Astor $500,000 in five per cent stock, specially issued, in surrender of his claim.14  Thus were the whole people taxed to buy, at an exorbitant price, the claim of a man who had got it by artifice and whose estate eventually applied the interest and principal of that stock to buying land in New York City.  Thus also can a considerable part of the Astor fortune be traced to Adolphus Phillips, son of Frederick, the partner, protector and chief spoil sharer of Captain Burgess, sea pirate, and whose estate, the Phillips manor, had been obtained by bribing Fletcher, the royal governor.

But while Astor gradually appropriated vast tracts of land in Wisconsin, Missouri, Iowa and other parts of the West, and levied his toll on one-third of Putnam County, it was in New York City that he concentrated the great bulk of his real estate speculations.  To buy steadily on the scale that he did required a constant revenue.  This revenue, as we have seen, came from his fur trading methods and activities and the profits and privileges of his shipping.  But these factors do not explain his entire agencies in becoming a paramount landocrat.  One of these was the banking privilege — a privilege so ordained by law that it was one of the most powerful and insidious suctions for sapping the wealth created by the toil of the producers, and for enriching its owners at a most appalling sacrifice to the working and agricultural classes.  And above all, Astor in common with his class, made the most valuable asset of Law, whether exploiting the violation, or the enforcement, of it.

If we are to accept the superficial, perfunctory accounts of Astor’s real estate investments in New York City, then he will appear in the usual eulogistic light of a law loving, sagacious man engaged in a legitimate enterprise.  The truth, however, lies deeper than that — a truth which has been either un-discerned or glossed over by those conventional writers who, with a panderer’s instinct, give a wealth-worshiping era the thing it wants to read, not what it ought to know.  Although apparently innocent and in accord with the laws and customs of the times, Astor’s real estate transactions were inseparably connected with consecutive evasions, trickery, frauds and violations of law.  Extraordinarily favorable as the law was to the propertied classes, even that law was constantly broken by the very classes to whom it was so partial.

Simultaneously, while reaping large revenues from his fur trade among the Indians in both the East and West, Astor was employing a different kind of fraud in using the powers of city and State government in New York in obtaining, for practically nothing, enormously valuable grants of land and other rights and privileges which added to the sum total of his growing wealth.

CORRUPT GRANTS OF CITY LAND.

In this procedure he was but doing what a number of other contemporaries such as Peter Goelet, the Rhinelanders, the Lorillards, the Schermerhorns and other men who then began to found powerful landed families, were doing at the same time.  The methods by which these men secured large areas of land, now worth huge sums, were unquestionably fraudulent, although the definite facts are not as wholly available as are, for instance, those which related to Fletcher’s granting vast estates for bribes in the seventeenth century, or the bribery which corrupted the various New York legislatures beginning in the year 1805.  Nevertheless, considering the character of the governing politicians, and the scandals that ensued from the granting and sales of New York City land a century or more ago, it is reasonably certain that corrupt means were used.  The student of the times cannot escape from this conclusion, particularly as it is borne out by many confirming circumstances.

New York City, at one time, owned a very large area of land which was fraudulently granted or sold to private individuals.  Considerable of this granting or selling was done during the years when the corrupt Benjamin Romaine was City Controller.  Romaine was so badly involved in a series of scandals arising from the grants and corrupt sales of city land, that in 1806 the Common Council, controlled by his own party, the Tammany machine, found it necessary to remove him from the office of City Controller for malfeasance. 14a  The specific charge was that he had fraudulently obtained valuable city land in the heart of the city without paying for it.  Something had to be done to still public criticism, and Romaine was sacrificed.  But, in fact, he was far from being the only venal official concerned in the current frauds.  These frauds continued no matter which party or what set of officials were in power.  Several years after Romaine was removed, John Bingham, a powerful member of the Aldermanic Committee on Finance, which passed upon and approved these various land grants, was charged by public investigators with having caused the city to sell to his brother-in-law land which he later influenced the city administration to buy back at an exorbitant price.  Spurred by public criticism the Common Council demanded its re-conveyance. 15  It is more than evident — it is indisputable — from the records and the public scandals, that the successive city administrations were corruptly conducted.  The conservative newspaper comments alone of the period indicate this clearly, if nothing else does.

A PROCESS OF SPOLIATION.

Neither Astor nor Goelet were directly active members of the changing political cliques which controlled the affairs of the city.  It is likely that they bore somewhat the same relation to these cliques that the politico-industrial magnates and financiers of today do ;  to all appearances distinctly apart from participation in politics, and yet by means of money, having a strong or commanding influence in the background.  But the Rhinelander brothers, William and Frederick, were integral members of the political machine in power.  Thus we find that in 1803, William Rhinelander was elected Assessor for the Fifth Ward (a highly important and sumptuous office at that time), while both he and Frederick were, at the same time, appointed inspectors of elections.16

The action of the city officials in disposing of city land to themselves, to political accomplices and to favorites (who, it is probable, although not a matter of proof, paid bribes) took two forms.  One was the granting of land under water, the other the granting of city real estate.  At that time the configuration of Manhattan Island was such that it was marked by ponds, streams and marshes, while the marginal lines of the Hudson River and the East River extended much further inland than now.  When an individual got what was called a water grant, it meant land under shallow water, where he had the right to build bulk-heads and wharves and to fill in and make solid ground.  Out of these water grants was created property now worth hundreds upon hundreds of millions of dollars.  The value at that time was not great, but the prospective value was immense.  This fact was recognized in the official reports of the day, which set forth how rapidly the city’s population and commerce were increasing.  As for city land as such, the city not only owned large tracts by reason of old grants and confiscations, but it constantly came into possession of more because of non-payment of taxes.

The excuses by which the city officials covered their short-sighted or fraudulent grants of the water rights and the city land were various.  One was that the gifts were for the purpose of assisting religious institutions.  This, however, was but an occasional excuse.  The principal excuse which was persisted in for forty years was that the city needed revenue.  This was a fact.  The succeeding city administrations so corruptly and extravagantly squandered the city’s money that the city was constantly in debt.  Perhaps this debt was created for the very purpose of having a plausible ground for disposing of city land.  So it was freely charged at that time.

THE CITY CREATES LANDLORDS.

Let us see how the religious motive worked.  On June 10, 1794, the city gave to Trinity Church a water grant covering all that land from Washington street to the North River between Chambers and Reade streets.  The annual rent was one shilling per running foot after the expiration of forty-two years from June 10, 1794.  Thus, for forty-two years, no rent was charged.  Shortly after the passage of this grant, Trinity Church conveyed it to William Rhinelander, and also all that ground between Jay and Harrison streets, from Greenwich street to the North River.  By a subsequent arrangement with Trinity Church and the city, all of this land as well as certain other Trinity land became William Rhinelander’s property ;  and then, by agreement of the Common Council on May 29, 1797, and confirmation of Nov. 16, 1807, he was given all rights to the land water between high and low water mark, bounding his property, for an absurdly low rental.17  These water grants were subsequently filled in and became of enormous value.

Astor was as energetic as Rhinelander in getting grants from the city officials.  In 1806 he obtained two of large extent on the East Side — on Mangin street between Stanton and Houston streets, and on South street between Peck Slip and Dover street.  On May 30, 1808, upon a favorable report handed in by the Finance Committee, of which the notorious John Bingham was a member, Astor received an extensive grant along the Hudson bounding the old Burr estate which had come into his possession.18  In 1810 he received three more water grants in the vicinity of Hubert, Laight, Charlton, Hammersly and Clarkson streets, and on April 28, 1828, three at Tenth avenue, Twelfth, Thirteenth, Fourteenth and Fifteenth streets.  These were some of the grants that he received.  But they do not include the land in the heart of the city that he was constantly buying from private owners or getting by the evident fraudulent connivance of the city officials.

Having obtained the water grants and other land by fraud, what did the grantees next proceed to do ?  They had them filled in, not at their own expense, but largely at the expense of the municipality.  Sunken lots were filled in, sewers placed, and streets opened, regulated and graded at but the merest minimum of expense to these landlords.  By fraudulent collusion with the city authorities they foisted much of the expense upon the taxpayers.  How much money the city lost by this process in the early decades of the nineteenth century was never known.  But in 1855 Controller Flagg submitted to the Common Council an itemized statement for the five years from 1850 in which he referred to “ the startling fact that the city’s payments, in a range of five years [for filling in sunken lots, regulating and grading streets, etc.], exceed receipts by the sum of more than two millions of dollars.”19

MANY PARTICIPANTS IN 
THE CURRENT FRAUDS.

In the case of most of these so-called water fronts, there was usually a trivial rental attached.  Nearly always, however, this was commuted upon payment of a small designated sum, and a full and clear title was then given by the city.  In this rush to get water-grants — grants many of which are now solid land filled with business and residential buildings — many of the ancestors of those families which pride themselves upon their exclusive air participated.  The Lorillards, the Goelets, William F. Havemeyer, Cornelius Vanderbilt, W.H. Webb, W.H. Kissam, Robert Lenox, Schermerhorn, James Roosevelt, William E. Dodge, Jr. — all of these and many others — not omitting Astor’s American Fur Company — at various times down to, and including the period of, the monumentally corrupt Tweed “ring,” got grants from corrupt city administrations.  Some of these water rights, that is to say, such fragmentary parts of them as pertained to wharves and bulkheads, New York City, in recent years, has had to buy back at exorbitant prices.  From the organization of the Dock Department down to 1906 inclusive, New York City had expended $70,000,000 for the purchase of bulkhead and wharf property and for construction.

During all the years from 1800 on, Astor, in conjunction with other landholders, was manipulating the city government not less than the State and Federal Government.  Now he gets from the Board of Aldermen title to a portion of this or that old country road on Manhattan which the city closes up ;  again and again he gets rights of land under water.  He constantly solicits the Board of Aldermen for this or that right or privilege and nearly always succeeds.  No property or sum is too small for his grasp.  In 1832, when Eighth avenue, from Thirteenth to Twenty-third streets is graded down and the earth removed is sold by the city to a contractor for $3,049.44, Astor, Stephen D. Beekman and Jacob Taylor petition that each get a part of the money, for earth removed from in front of their lots.  This is considered such a petty attempt at defrauding, that the Aldermen call it an “unreasonable petition ” and refuse to accede.20  In 1834 the Aldermen allow him a part of the old Hurlgate road, and Rhinelander a part of the Southampton road.  Not a year passes but that he does not get some new right or privilege from the city government.  At his request some streets are graded and improved ;  the improvement of such other streets as is not to his interest to have improved is delayed.  Here sewers are placed ;  there they are refused.  Every function of city administration was incessantly used by him.  The cumulative effect of this class use of government was to give him and others a constant succession of grants and privileges that now have a prodigious value.

But it should be noted that those who thus benefited, singularly enjoyed the advantages of laws and practices.  For city land that they bought they were allowed to pay on easy terms ;  not infrequently the city had to bring action for final payment.  But the tenants of these landlords had to pay rent on the day that it fell due, or within a few days of the time ;  they could not be in arrears more than three days without having to face dispossess proceedings.  Nor was this all the difference.  On land which they corruptly obtained from the city and which, to a large extent, they fraudulently caused to be filled in, regulated, graded or otherwise improved at the expense of the whole community, the landlords refused to pay taxes promptly, just as they refused to pay them on land that they had bought privately.  What was the result ?  “ Some of our wealthiest citizens,” reported the Controller in 1831, “ are in the habit of postponing the payment of taxes for six months and more, and the Common Council are necessitated to borrow money on interest to meet the ordinary disbursements of the city.”21  If a man of very moderate means were backward in payment of taxes, the city promptly closed him out, and if a tenant of any of these delinquent landlords were dispossessed for non-payment of rent, the city it was which undertook the process of eviction.  The rich landlord, however, could do as he pleased, since all government represented his interests and those of his class.  Instead of the punishment for non-payment of taxes being visited upon him, it was imposed upon the whole community in the form of interest-bearing bonds.

PILLAGE, PROFITS AND LAND.

The money that Astor secured by robbing the Indians and exploiting the workers by means of monopolies, he thus put largely into land.  In 1810, a story runs, he offers to sell a Wall Street lot for $8,000.  The price is so low that a buyer promptly appears.  “Yes, you are astonished,” Astor says.  “ But see what I intend to do with that eight thousand dollars.  That Wall Street lot, it is true, will be worth twelve thousand dollars in a few years.  But I shall take that eight thousand dollars and buy eighty lots above Canal street and by the time your one lot is worth twelve thousand dollars, my eighty lots will be worth eighty thousand dollars.”  So goes one of the fine stories told to illustrate his foresight, and to prove that his fortune came exclusively from that faculty and from his industry.

This version bears all the impress of being undoubtedly a fraud.  Astor was remarkably secretive and dissembling, and never revealed his plans to anyone.  That he bought the lots is true enough, but his attributed loquacity is mythical and is the invention of some gushing eulogist.  At that time he was buying for $200 or $300 each many lots on lower Broadway, then, for the most part, an unoccupied waste.  What he was counting upon was the certain growth of the city and the vastly increasing values not that he would give his land, but which would accrue from the labor of an enlarged population.  These lots are now occupied by crowded business buildings and are valued at from $300,000 to $400,000 each.

Throughout those years in the first decade of the nineteenth century he was constantly buying land on Manhattan Island.  Practically all of it was bought, not with the idea of using it, but of holding it and allowing future populations to make it a thousand times more valuable.  An exception was his country estate of thirteen acres at Hurlgate (Hellgate) in the vicinity of Sixtieth street and the East River.  It was curious to look back at the fact that less than a century ago the upper regions of Manhattan Island were filled with country estates — regions now densely occupied by huge tenement houses and some private dwellings.  In those days, not less than in these, a country seat was considered a necessary appendage to the possessions of a rich man.  Astor bought that Hurlgate estate as a country seat ;  but as such it was long since discontinued although the land comprising it has never left the hold of the Astor family.

What were the intrinsic circumstances of the means by which he bought land, now worth hundreds of millions of dollars ?  For once, we get a gleam of the truth, but a gleam only, in the “ popular writer’s ” account when be says :  “ John Jacob Astor’s record is constantly crossed by embarrassed families, prodigal sons, mortgages and foreclosure sales.  Many of the victims of his foresight were those highest in church and state.  He thus acquired for $75,000 one-half of Governor George Clinton’s splendid Greenwich country place [in the old Greenwich village on the west side of Manhattan Island]. . . . After the Governor’s death, he kept persistently at the heirs, lent them money and acquired additional slices of the family property. . . . Nearly two-thirds of the Clinton farm is now held by Astor’s descendants, and is covered by scores of business buildings, from which is derived an annual income estimated at $500,000.”

THE FATE OF OTHERS HIS GAIN.

In this transaction we see the beginnings of that period of conquest on the part of the very rich using their surplus capital in effacing the less rich — a period which really opened with Astor and which has been vastly intensified in recent times.  Clinton was accounted a rich man in his day, but he was a pigmy in that respect compared to Astor.  With his incessant inflow of surplus wealth, Astor was in a position where on the instant he could take advantage of the difficulties of less rich men and take over to himself their property.  A large amount of Astor’s money was invested in mortgages.  In times of periodic financial and industrial distress, the mortgagees were driven to extremities and could no longer keep up their payments.  These were the times that Astor waited for, and it was in such times that he stepped in and possessed himself, at comparatively small expense, of large additional tracts of land.

It was this way that he became the owner of what was then the Cosine farm, extending on Broadway from Fifty-third to Fifty-seventh streets and westward to the Hudson River.  This property, which he got for $23,000 by foreclosing a mortgage, is now in the very heart of the city, filled with many business, and every variety of residential, buildings, and is rated as worth $6,000,000.  By much the same means he acquired ownership of the Eden farm in the same vicinity, coursing along Broadway north from Forty-second street and slanting over to the Hudson River.  This farm lay under pledges for debt and attachments for loans.  Suddenly Astor turned up with a third interest in an outstanding mortgage, foreclosed, and for a total payment of $25,000 obtained a sweep of property now covered densely with huge hotels, theaters, office buildings, stores and long vistas of residences and tenements — a property worth at the very least $25,000,000.  Any one with sufficient security in land who sought to borrow money would find Astor extremely accommodating.  But woe betide the hapless borrower, whoever he was, if he failed in his obligations to the extent of even a fraction of the requirements covered by law !  Neither personal friendship, religious considerations nor the slightest feelings of sympathy availed.

But where law was insufficient or non-existent, new laws were created either to aggrandize the powers of landlordship, or to seize hold of land or enhance its value, or to get extraordinary special privileges in the form of banking charters.  And here it is necessary to digress from the narrative of Astor’s land transactions and advert to his banking activities, for it was by reason of these subordination, as well as by his greater trade revenues, that he was enabled so successfully to pursue his career of wealth-gathering.  The circumstances as to the origin of certain powerful banks in which he and other landholders and traders were large stockholders, the methods and powers of those banks, and their effect upon the great body of the people, are component parts of the analytic account of his operations.  Not a single one of Astor’s biographers has mentioned his banking connections.  Yet it is of the greatest importance to describe them, inasmuch as they were closely intertwined with his trade, on the one hand, and with his land acquisitions, on the other.


CHAPTER IV

THE RAMIFICATIONS OF 
THE ASTOR FORTUNE

Astor flourished at that precise time when the traders and landowners, flushed with revenues, reached out for the creation and control of the highly important business of professionally dealing in money, and of dictating, personally and directly, what the supply of the people's money should be.

This signalized the next step in the aggrandizement of individual fortunes.  The few who could center in themselves, by grace of Government, the banking and manipulation of the people's money and the restricting or inflating of money issues, were immediately vested with an extraordinary power.  It was a sovereign power at once coercive and proscription, and a mighty instrument for transferring the produce of the many to a small and exclusive coterie.  Not merely over the labor of the whole working class did this gripping process extend, but it was severely felt by that large part of the landowning and trading class which was excluded from holding the same privileges.  The banker became the master of the master.  In that fierce, pervading competitive strife, the banks were the final exploiters.  Sparsely organized and wholly unprotected, the worker was in the complete power of the trader, manufacturer and landowner ;  in turn, such of these divisions of the propertied class as were not themselves sharers in the ownership of banks were at the mercy of the banking institutions.

At any time upon some pretext or other, the banks could arbitrarily refuse the latter class credit or accommodation, or harass its victims in other ways equally as destructive.  As business was largely done in expectations of payment, in other words, on credit, as it is now, this was a serious, often a desperate, blow to the lagging or embarrassed brothers in trade.  Banks were virtually empowered by law to ruin or enrich any individual or set of individuals.  As the banks were then founded and owned by men who were themselves traders or landholders, this power was crushingly used against competitors.  Armed with the strong power of law, the banks overawed the mercantile world, thrived on the industry, misfortune or ruin of others, and swayed politics and elections.  The bank men loaned money to themselves at an absurdly low rate of interest.  But for loans of money to all others they demanded a high rate of interest which, in periods of commercial distress, overwhelmed the borrowers.  Nominally banks were restricted to a certain standard rate of interest ;  but by various subterfuges they easily evaded these provisions and exacted usurious rates.

BANKS AND THEIR POWER.

These, however, were far from being the worst features.  The most innocent of their great privileges was that of playing fast and loose with the money confidingly entrusted to their care by a swarm of depositors who either worked for it, or for the matter of that, often stole it ;  bankers, like pawnbrokers, ask no questions.  The most remarkable of their vested powers was that of manufacturing money.  The industrial manufacturer could not make goods unless he had the plant, the raw material and the labor.  But the banker, somewhat like the fabled alchemists, could transmute airy nothing into bank-note money, and then, by law, force its acceptance.  The lone trader or landholder unsupported by a partnership with law could not fabricate money.  But let trader and landholder band in a company, incorporate, then persuade, wheedle or bribe a certain entity called a legislature to grant them a certain bit of paper styled a charter, and lo! they were instantly transformed into money manufacturers.

A MANDATE TO PREY.

The simple mandate of law was sufficient authorization for them to prey upon the whole world outside of their charmed circle.  With this scrap of paper they could go forth on the highways of commerce and over the farms and drag in, by the devious, absorbent processes of the banking system, a great part of the wealth created by the actual producers.  As it was with taxation, so was it with the burdens of this system ;  they fell largely upon the worker, whether in the shop or on the farm.  When the business man and the landowner were compelled to pay exorbitant rates of interest they but apparently had to meet the demands.  What these classes really did was to throw the whole of these extra impositions upon the working class in the form of increased prices for necessaries and merchandise and in augmented rents.

But how were these State or Government authorizations, called charters, to be obtained ?  Did not the Federal Constitution prohibit States from giving the right to banks to issue money ?  Were not private money factories specifically barred by that clause of the Constitution which declared that no State “ shall coin money, emit bills of credit, or make anything but gold or silver a tender in payment of debts ? ”

Here, again, the power of class domination of Government came into compelling effect.  The onward sweep of the trading class was not to be balked by such a trifling obstacle as a Constitutional provision.  At all times when the Constitution has stood in the way of commercial aims it has been abrogated, not by repeal nor violent overthrow, but by the effective expedient of judicial interpretation.  The trading class demanded State created banks with power of issuing money ;  and, as the courts have invariably in the long run responded to the interests and decrees of the dominant class, a decision was quickly forthcoming in this case to the effect that “ bills of credit ” were not meant to cover banknotes.  This was a new and surprising construction ;  but judicial decision and precedent made it virtually law, and law a thousandfold more binding than any Constitutional insertion.

COURTS AND CONSTITUTION.

The trading class had already learned the importance of the principle that while it was essential to control lawmaking bodies, it was imperative to have as their auxiliary the bodies that interpreted law.  To a large extent the United States since then has lived not under legislative-made law, but under a purely separate and extraneous form of law which has superseded the legislature product, namely, court law.  Although nowhere in the United States Constitution is there even the suggestion that courts shall make law, yet this past century and more they have been gradually building up a formidable code of interpretations which substantially ranks as the most commanding kind of law.  And these interpretations have, on the whole, consistently followed, and kept pace with, the changing interests of the dominant class, whether traders, slaveholders, or the present trusts.

This decision of the august courts opened the way for the greatest orgy of corruption and the most stupendous frauds.  In New York, Massachusetts, New Jersey, Pennsylvania, Maryland, and other States a continuous rush to get bank charters ensued.  Most of the legislatures were composed of men who, while perhaps, not innately corrupt, were easily seduced by the corrupt temptations held out by the traders.  There was a deep seated hostility, in many parts of the country, on the part of the middling tradesmen — the shopkeepers and the petty merchants — to any laws calculated to increase the power and the privileges of the superior traders and the landowners.  Among the masses of workers, most of whom were, however, disfranchised, any attempt to vest the rich with new privileges, was received with the bitterest resentment.  But the legislatures were approachable ;  some members who were put there by the rich families needed only the word as to how they should vote, while others, representing both urban and rural communities, were swayed by bribes.  By one means or another the traders and landholders forced the various legislatures into doing what was wanted.

Omitting the records of other States, a few salient facts as to what took place in New York State will suffice to give a clear idea of some of the methods of the trading class in pressing forward their conquests, in hurling aside every impediment, whether public opinion or law, and in creating new laws which satisfied their extending plans for a ramification of profit-producing interests.  If forethought, an unswerving aim and singleness of execution mean anything, then there was something sternly impressive in the way in which this rising capitalist class went forward to snatch what it sought, and what it believed to be indispensable to its plans.  There was no hesitation, nor were there any scruples as to niceties of methods ;  the end in view was all that counted ;  so long as that was attained, the means used were considered paltry side-issues.  And, indeed, herein lies the great distinction of action between the world-old propertied classes and the contending proletariat ;  for whereas the one have always campaigned irrespective of law and particularly by bribery, intimidation, repression and force, the working class has had to confine its movement strictly to the narrow range of laws which were expressly prepared against it and the slightest violation of which has called forth the summary vengeance of a society ruled actually, if not theoretically, by the very propertied classes which set at defiance all law.

THE BANKING FRAUDS BEGIN.

The chartered monopoly held by the traders who controlled the United States Bank was not accepted passively by others of the commercial class, who themselves wanted financial engines of the same character.  The doctrine of State's rights served the purpose of these excluded capitalists as well as it did that of the slaveholders.

The States began a course of reeling out bank charters.  By 1799 New York City had one bank, the Bank of New York ;  this admixed the terrorism of trade and politics so overtly that presently an opposition application for a charter was made.  This solitary bank was run by some of the old landowning families who fully understood the danger involved in the triumph of the democratic ideas represented by Jefferson ;  a danger far overestimated, however, since win as democratic principles did, the propertied class continued its victorious march, for the simple reason that property was able to divert manhood suffrage to its own account, and to aggrandize itself still further on the ruins of every subsequent similar reform expedient.  What the agitated masses, for the most part, of that period could not comprehend was that they who hold the possession of the economic resources will indubitably sway the politics of a country, until such time as the proletariat, no longer divided but thoroughly conscious, organized, and aggressive, will avail itself of its majority vote to transfer the powers of government to itself.  The Bank of New York injected itself virulently into politics and fought the spread of democratic ideas with sordid but effective weapons.  If a merchant dared support what it denounced as heretical doctrines, the bank at once blacklisted him by rejecting his notes when he needed cash most.

It was now that Aaron Burr, that adroit leader of the opposition party, stepped in.  Seconded or instigated by certain traders, he set out to get one of those useful and invaluable bank charters for his backers.  The explanation of how he accomplished the act is thus given :  Taking advantage of the epidemic of yellow fever then desolating New York City, he, with much preliminary of philanthropic motives, introduced a bill for the apparent beneficent purpose of diminishing the future possibility of the disease by incorporating a company, called the Manhattan Company, to supply pure, wholesome water.  Supposing that the charter granted nothing more than this, the explanation goes on, the Legislature passed the bill, and was most painfully surprised and shocked when the fact came out that the measure had been so deftly drawn, that it, in fact, granted an unlimited charter, conferring banking powers on the company.1

This explanation is probably shallow and deficient.  It is much more likely that bribery was resorted to, considering the fact that the granting of every successive bank charter was invariably accompanied by bribery.  Six years later the Mercantile Bank received a charter for a thirteen years' period — a charter which, it was openly charged by certain members of the Assembly, was secured by bribery.  These charges were substantially proved by the testimony before a legislative investigating committee.2  In 1811 the Mechanics' Bank was chartered with a time limit under circumstances indicating bribery.

Indeed, so often was bribing done and so pronounced were charges of corruption at frequent sessions of the Legislature, that in 1812, the Assembly, in an heroic spasm of impressive virtue, passed a resolution compelling each member to pledge himself that he had neither taken, nor would take, “ any reward or profit, direct or indirect, for any vote on any measure.”3  This resolution was palpably intended to blind the public ;  for, in that identical year, the Bank of America received a charter amid charges of flagrant corruption.  One Assemblyman declared under oath that he had been offered the sum of $500, “ besides, a handsome present for his vote.”4  All of the banks, except the Manhattan, had limited charters ;  measures for the renewal of these were practically all put through by bribery.5  Thus, in 1818, the charter of the Merchants' Bank was renewed until 1832, and renewed after that.  The chartering of the Chemical Bank (that staid and most eminently respectable and solid New York institution of today) was accomplished by bribery.  The Chemical Bank was an outgrowth of the Chemical Manufacturing Company, the plant and business of which were bought expressly as an excuse to get a banking auxiliary.  The Goelet brothers were among the founders of this bank.  In fact, many of the great landed fortunes were inseparably associated with the frauds of the banking system ;  money from land was used to bribe legislatures, and money made from the banks was employed in buying more land.  The promoters of the Chemical Bank set aside a considerable sum of money and $50,000 in stock for the bribery fund.6  No sooner had it received its charter than it began to turn out reams of paper money, based upon no value, which paper was paid as wages to its employees as well as circulated generally.  So year after year the bribery went on industriously, without cessation.

BRIBERY A CRIME IN NAME ONLY.

Were the bribers ever punished, their illicitly gotten charters declared forfeited, and themselves placed under the ban of virtuous society ?  Far, very far, from it !  The men who did the bribing were of the very pinnacle of social power, elegance and position, or quickly leaped to that height by reason of their wealth.  They were among the foremost landholders and traders of the day.  By these and a wide radius of similar means, they amassed wealth or greatly increased wealth already accumulated.  The ancestors of some of the most conspicuous multimillionaire families of the present were deeply involved in the perpetration of all of those continuous frauds and crimes — Peter Goelet and his sons, Peter P. and Robert, for instance, and Jacob Lorillard, who, for many years, was president of the Mechanics' Bank.  No stigma attached to these wealth-grasper's.  Their success as possessors of riches at once, by the automatic processes of a society which enthroned wealth, elevated them to be commanding personages in trade, politics, orthodoxy and the highest social spheres.  The cropped convict, released from prison, was followed everywhere by the jeers and branding of a society which gloated over his downfall and which forever reminded him of his infamy.  But the men who waded on to wealth through the muck of base practices and by means of crimes a million fold more insidious and dangerous than the offense of the convict, were not only honored as leading citizens, but they became the extolled and unquestioned dictators of that supreme trading society which made modes, customs and laws.

It was a society essentially built upon money ;  consequently he who was dexterous enough to get possession of the spoils, experienced no difficulty in establishing his place among the elect and anointed.  His frauds were forgotten or ignored ;  only the fact that he was a rich man was remembered, And yet, what is more natural than to seek, and accept, the obeisance lavished upon property, in a scheme of society where property is crowned as the ruling power ?  In the rude centuries previously mankind exalted physical prowess ;  he who had the greatest strength and wielded the deftest strokes became victor of the judicial combat and gathered in laurels and property.  But now we have arrived at the time when the cunning of mind supplants the cunning of muscle ;  bribery takes the place of brawn ;  the contestants fight with statutes instead of swords.  And this newer plan, which some have decried as degenerate, is a great advance over the old, for thereby has brute force been legally abandoned in personal quarrels at least, and that cunning of mind which has held sway, is the first evidence of the reign of mind, which from a low order, will universally develop noble and super eminent qualities charged with the good, and that alone, of the human race.

ASTOR'S BANKING ACTIVITIES.

With this preliminary sketch, we can now proceed to a consideration of how Astor profited from the banking system.  We see that constantly the bold spirits of the trading class, with a part of the money made or plundered in some direction or other, were bribing representative bodies to give them exceptional rights and privileges which, in turn, were made the fertile basis for further spoliation.  Astor was a stockholder in at least four banks, the charters of which had been obtained or renewed by trickery and fraud, or both.  He owned 1,000 shares of the capital stock of the Manhattan Company ;  1,000 of the Merchant's Bank ;  500 of the Bank of America ;  1,604 of the Mechanic's Bank.  He also owned at one time considerable stock in the National Bank, the charter of which, it was strongly suspected, had been obtained by bribery.

There is no evidence that he, himself, did the actual bribing or was in any way concerned in it.  In all of the legislative investigations following charges of bribery, the invariable practice was to throw the blame upon the wicked lobbyists, while professing the most naive astonishment that any imputations should be cast upon any of the members of the honorable Legislature.  As for the bribers behind the scenes, their names seldom or never were brought out or divulged.  In brief, these investigations were all of that rose-water order, generally termed “ whitewashing.”  But whether Astor personally bribed or not, he at any rate consciously profited from the results of bribery ;  and, moreover, it is not probable that his methods in the East were different, except in form, from the debauching and exploitation that he made a system of in the fur regions.  It is not outside the realm of reasonable conjecture to suppose that he either helped to debauch, or connived at the corruption of legislatures, just as in another way he debauched Indian tribes.

Furthermore his relations with Burr in one notorious transaction, are sufficient to justify the conclusion that he held the closest business relations with that political adventurer who lived next door to him at No. 221 Broadway.  This transaction was one which was partially the outcome of the organization of the Manhattan Bank and was a source of millions of dollars of profit to Astor and to his descendants.

A century or more ago Trinity Church owned three times the extent of even the vast real estate that it now holds.  A considerable part of this was the gift of that royal governor Fletcher, who, as has been set forth, was such a master-hand at taking bribes.  There long existed a contention upon the part of New York State, a contention embodied in numerous official records, that the land held for centuries by Trinity Church was usurped ;  that Trinity's title was invalid and that the real title vested in the people of the city of New York.  In 1854-55 the Land Commissioners of New York State, deeply impressed by the facts as marshaled by Rutger B. Miller,7 recommended that the State bring suit.  But with the filing of Trinity's reply, mysterious influences intervened and the matter was dropped.  These influences are frequently referred to in aldermanic documents.

To go back, however :  In 1767 Trinity Church leased to Abraham Mortier, for ninety-nine years, at a total annual rental of $269 a year, a stretch of land comprising 465 lots in what is now the vicinity bounded by Greenwich, Spring and Hudson streets.  Mortier used it as a country place until 1797 when the New York Legislature, upon the initiative of Burr, developed a consuming curiosity as to how Trinity Church was expending its income.  This was a very ticklish question with the pious vestrymen of Trinity, as it was generally suspected that they were commingling business and piety in a way that might, if known, cause them some trouble.  The law, at that time, restricted the annual income of Trinity Church from its property to $12,000 a year.  A committee of investigation was appointed ;  of this committee Burr was made chairman.

HOW ASTOR SECURED A LEASE.

Burr never really made any investigation.  Why ?  The reason soon came out, when Burr turned up with a transfer of the Mortier lease to himself.  He at once obtained from the Manhattan Bank a $38,000 loan, pledging the lease as security.  When his duel with Hamilton forced Burr to flee the country, Astor promptly came along and took the lease off his hands.  Astor, it was said, paid him $32,000 for it, subject to the Manhattan Bank's mortgage.  At any rate, Astor now held this extraordinarily valuable lease.8  He immediately re-leased it in lots ;  and as the city fast grew, covering the whole stretch with population and buildings, the lease was a source of great revenue to him and to his heirs.9  As a Lutheran, Astor could not be a vestryman of Trinity Church.  Anthony Lispenard, however, it may be passingly noted, was a vestryman, and, as such, mixed piety and business so well, that his heirs became possessed of millions of dollars by the mere fact that in 1779, when a vestryman, he got a lease, for eighty-three years of eighty-one Trinity lots adjacent to the Astor leased land, at a total annual rental of $177.50.10

It was by the aid of the banking system that the trading class was greatly enabled to manipulate the existing and potential resources of the country and to extend invaluable favors to themselves.  In this system Astor was a chief participant.  For many years the banks, especially in New York State, were empowered by law to issue paper money to the extent of three times the amount of their capital.  The actual specie was seized hold of by the shippers, and either hoarded, or exported in quantities to Asia or Europe which, of course, would not handle paper money.  By 1819 the banks in New York had issued $12,500,000, and the total amount of specie to redeem this fiat stuff amounted to only $2,000,000.  These banknotes were nothing more or less than irresponsible promises to pay.  What became of them ?

WHAT THE WORKER GOT AS WAGES.

What, indeed, became of them ?  They were imposed upon the working class as payment for labor.  Although these banknotes were subject to constant depreciation, the worker had to accept them as though they were full value.  But when the worker went to buy provisions or pay rent, he was compelled to pay one-third, and often one-half, as much as the value represented by those banknotes.  Sometimes, in crises, he could not get them cashed at all ;  they became pitiful souvenirs in his hands.  This fact was faintly recognized by a New York Senate Committee when it reported in 1819 that every artifice in the wit of man had been devised to find ways of putting these notes into circulation ;  that when the merchant got this depreciated paper, he “ saddled it upon the departments of productive labor.”  “ The farmer and the mechanic alike,” went on the report, “ have been invited to make loans and have fallen victims to the avarice of the banker.  The result has been the banishment of metallic currency, the loss of commercial confidence, fictitious capital, increase of civil prosecutions and multiplication of crimes.”11  What the committee did not see was that by this process those in control of the banks had, with no expenditure, possessed themselves of a considerable part of the resources of the country and had made the worker yield up twice and three times as much of the produce of his labor as he had to give before the system was started.

The large amount of paper money, without any basis of value whatever, was put out at a heavy rate of interest.  When the merchant paid his interest, he charged it up as extra cost on his wares ;  and when the worker came to buy these same wares which he or some fellow-worker had made, he was charged a high price which included three things all thrown upon him :  rent, interest and profit.  The banks indirectly sucked in a large portion of these three factors.  And so thoroughly did the banks control legislation that they were not content with the power of issuing spurious paper money ;  they demanded, and got through, an act exempting bank stock from taxation.

Thus year after year this system went on, beggaring great numbers of people, enriching the owners of the banks and virtually giving them a life and death power over the worker, the farmer and the floundering, struggling small business man alike.  The laws were but slightly altered.  “The great profits of the banks,” reported a New York Senate Committee on banks and insurance in 1834, “arise from their issues.  It is this privilege which enables them, in fact, to coin money, to substitute their evidences of debt for a metallic currency and to loan more than their actual capitals.  A bank of $100,000 capital is permitted to loan $250,000; and thus receive an interest on twice and a half the amount actually invested.”12

THE WORKINGMEN'S PARTY PROTEST.

It cannot be said that all of the workingmen were apathetic, or that some did not see through the fraud of the system.  They had good reason for the deepest indignation and exasperation.  The terrible injustices piled upon them from every quarter — the low wages that they were forced to accept, often in depreciated or worthless banknotes, the continually increasing exaction's of the landlords, the high prices squeezed out of them by monopolies, the arbitrary discrimination's of law — these were not without their effect.  The Workingmen's Party, formed in 1829 in New York City, was the first and most ominous of these proletarian uprisings.  Its resolutions read like a proletarian Declaration of Independence, and would unquestionably have resulted in the most momentous agitation, had it not been that it was smothered by its leaders, and also because the slavery issue long obscured purely economic questions.  “Resolved,” ran its resolutions adopted at Military Hall, Oct. 19, 1829,

in the opinion of this meeting, that the first appropriation of the soil of the State to private and exclusive possession was eminently and barbarously unjust.  That it was substantially feudal in its character, inasmuch as those who received enormous and unequal possessions were lords and those who received little or nothing were vassals.  That hereditary transmission of wealth on the one hand and poverty on the other, has brought down to the present generation all the evils of the feudal system, and that, in our opinion, is the prime source of all our calamities.
After declaring that the Workingmen's Party would oppose all exclusive privileges, monopolies and exemptions, the resolutions proceeded :

We consider it an exclusive privilege for one portion of the community to have the means of education in colleges, while another is restricted to common schools, or, perhaps, by extreme poverty, even deprived of the limited education to be acquired in those establishments.  Our voice, therefore, shall be raised in favor of a system of education which shall be equally open to all, as in a real republic, it should be.
Finally the resolutions told what the Workingmen's Party thought of the bankers and the banking system.  The bankers were denounced as “the greatest knaves, impostors and paupers of the age.”  The resolutions went on :

As banking is now conducted, the owners of the banks receive annually of the people of the State not less than two millions of dollars in their paper money (and it might as well be pewter money) for which there is and can be nothing provided for its redemption on demand. . . .
The mockery that went up from all that was held influential, respectable and stable when these resolutions were printed, was echoed far and wide.  They were looked upon first as a joke, and then, when the Workingmen's Party began to reveal its earnestness and strength, as an insolent challenge to constituted authority, to wealth and superiority, and as a menace to society.

RADICALISM VERSUS RESPECTABILITY.

The “ Courier and Enquirer,” owned by Webb and Noah, in the pay of the United States Bank, burst out into savage invective.  It held the Workingmen's Party up to opprobrium as an infidel crowd, hostile to the morals and the institutions of society, and to the rights of property.  Nevertheless the Workingmen's Party proceeded with an enthusiastic, almost ecstatic, campaign and polled 6,000 votes, a very considerable number compared to the whole number of voters at the time.

By 1831, however, it had gone out of existence.  The reason was that it allowed itself to be betrayed by the supineness, incompetence, and as some said, the treachery, of its leaders, who were content to accept from a Legislature controlled by the propertied interests various mollifying sops which slightly altered certain laws, but which in no great degree redounded to the benefit of the working class.  For a few bits of counterfeit, this splendid proletarian uprising, glowing with energy, enthusiasm and hope, allowed itself to be snuffed out of existence.

What a tragedy was there !  And how futile and tragic must inevitably be the fate of any similar movement which depends not upon itself, not upon its own intrinsic, collective strength and wisdom, but upon the say-so of leaders who come forward to assume leadership.  Representing only their own timidity of thought and cowardice of action, they often end by betraying the cause placed confidingly in their charge.  That class which for these immemorial generations has done the world's work, and as long has been plundered and oppressed and betrayed, thus had occasion to learn anew the bitter lesson taught by the wreckage of the past, that it is from itself that the emancipation must come ;  that it is itself which must essentially think, act and strike ;  that its forces, long torn asunder and dispersed, must be marshaled in invulnerable compactness and iron discipline ;  and so that its hosts may not again be routed by strategy, no man or set of men should be entrusted with the irrevocable power of executing its decrees, for too often has the courage, boldness and strength of the many been shackled or destroyed by the compromising weakness of the leaders.

THE PANIC OF 1837.

Passing over the Equal Rights movement in 1834 which was a diluted revival of the Workingmen's Party, and which, also, was turned into sterility by the treachery of its leaders, we arrive at the panic of 1837, the time when Astor, profiting from misfortune on every side, vastly increased his wealth.

The panic of 1837 was one of those periodic financial and industrial convulsions resulting from the chaos of capitalist administration.  No sooner had it commenced, than the banks refused to pay out any money, other than their worthless notes.  For thirty-three years they had not only enjoyed immense privileges, but they had used the powers of Government to insure themselves a monopoly of the business of manufacturing money.  In 1804 the Legislature of New York State had passed an extraordinary law, called the restraining act.  This prohibited, under severe penalties, all associations and individuals not only from issuing notes, but “ from receiving deposits, making discounts or transacting any other business which incorporated banks may or do transact.”  Thus the law not only legitimatized the manufacture of worthless money, but guaranteed a few banks a monopoly of that manufacture.  Another restraining act was passed in 1818.  The banks were invested with the sovereign privilege of depreciating the currency at their discretion, and were authorized to levy an annual tax upon the country, nearly equivalent to the interest on $200,000,000 of deposits and circulation.  On top of these acts, the Legislature passed various acts compelling the public authorities in New York City to deposit public money with the Manhattan Company.  This company, although, as we have seen, expressly chartered to supply pure water to the city of New York, utterly failed to do so ;  at one stage the city tried to have its charter revoked on the ground of failure to carry out its chartered function, but the courts decided in the company's favor.13

At the outbreak of the panic of 1837, the New York banks held more than $5,500,000 of public money.  When called upon to pay only about a million of that sum, or the premium on it, they refused.  But far worse was the experience of the general public.  When they frantically besieged the banks for their money, the bank officials filled the banks with heavily armed guards and plug-uglies with orders to fire on the crowd in case a rush was attempted.14

In every State conditions were the same.  In May, 1837, not less than eight hundred banks in the United States suspended payment, refusing a single dollar to the Government whose deposits of $30,000,000 they held, and to the people in general who held $120,000,000 of their notes.  No specie whatever was in circulation.  The country was deluged with small notes, colloquially termed shin plasters.  Of every form and every denomination from the alleged value of five cents to that of five dollars, they were issued by every business individual or corporation for the purpose of paying them off as wages to their employees.  The worker was forced to take them for his labor or starve.  Moreover, the shin plasters were so badly printed that it was not hard to counterfeit them.  The counterfeiting of them quickly became a regular business ;  immense quantities of the stuff were issued.  The worker never knew whether the bills paid him for his work were genuine or counterfeit, although essentially there was not any great difference in basic value between the two. 14a

THE RESULTING WIDESPREAD DESTITUTION.

Now the storm broke.  Everywhere was impoverishment, ruination and beggary.  Every bank official in New York City was subject to arrest for the most serious frauds and other crimes, but the authorities took no action.  On the contrary, so complete was the dominance of the banks over Government,15 that they hurriedly got the Legislature to pass an act practically authorizing a suspension of specie payments.  The consequences were appalling.  “Thousands of manufacturing, mercantile, and other useful establishments in the United States,” reported a New York Senate Committee, “have been broken down or paralyzed by the existing crisis....  In all our great cities numerous individuals, who, by a long course of regular business, had acquired a competency, have suddenly been reduced, with their families to beggary.”16  New York City was filled with the homeless, And unemployed.  In the early part of 1838 one-third of all the persons in New York City who subsisted by manual labor, were wholly or substantially without employment.  Not less than 10,000 persons were in utter poverty, and had no other means of surviving the winter than those afforded by the charity of neighbors.  The almshouses and other public and charitable institutions overflowed with inmates, and 10,000 sufferers were still not cared for.

The prevailing system, as was pointed out even by the conventional and futile reports of legislative committees, was one inevitably calculated to fill the country with beggars, vagrants and criminals.  This important fact was recognized, although in a remote way, by De Beaumont and De Tocqueville who, however, had no fundamental understanding of the deep causes, nor even of the meaning of the facts which they so accurately gathered.  In their elaborate work on the penitentiary system in the United States, published in 1833, they set forth that it was their conclusion that in the four States, New York, Massachusetts, Connecticut and Pennsylvania, the prison system of which they had fully investigated, almost all of those convicted for crimes from 1800 to 1830 were convicted for offenses against property.  In these four States, collectively, with a population amounting to one-third of that of the Union, not less than 91.29 out of every 100 convictions were for crimes against property, while only 8.66 of every 100 were for crimes against persons, and 4.05 of every 100 were for crimes against morals.  In New York State singly, 93.56 of every 100 convictions were for crimes against property and 6.26 for crimes against persons. 16a

PROPERTY AND CRIME.

Thus we see from these figures filled with such tragic eloquence, the economic impulse working at bottom, and the property system corrupting every form of society.  But here a vast difference is to be noted.  Just as in England the aristocracy for centuries had made the laws and had enforced the doctrine that it was they who should wield the police power of the State, so in the United States, to which the English system of jurisprudence had been transplanted, the propertied interests, constituting the aristocracy, made and executed the laws.  De Beaumont and De Tocqueville passingly observed that while the magistrates in the United States were plebeian, yet they followed out the old English system ;  in other words, they enforced laws which were made for, and by, the American aristocracy, the trading classes.

The views, aims and interests of these classes were so thoroughly entrenched in law that the fact did not escape the keen notice of these foreign investigators.  “ The Americans, descendants of the English,” they wrote, “ have provided in every respect for the rich and hardly at all for the poor. ... In the same country where the complainant is put in prison, the thief remains at liberty, if he can find bail.  Murder is the only crime whose authors are not protected.17 . . . The mass of lawyers see in this nothing contrary to their ideas of justice and injustice, nor even to their democratic institutions.”18

THE SYSTEM — HOW IT WORKED.

The system, then, frequently forced the destitute into theft and mendicancy.  What resulted ?  Laws, inconceivably harsh and brutal, enacted by, and in behalf of, property rights were enforced with a rigor which seems unbelievable were it not that the fact is verified by the records of thousands of cases.  Those convicted for robbery usually received a life sentence ;  they were considered lucky if they got off with five years.  The ordinary sentence for burglary was the same, with variations.  Forgery and grand larceny were punishable with long terms, ranging from five to seven years.  These were the laws in practically all of the States with slight differences.  But they applied to whites only.  The negro slave criminal had a superior standing in law, for the simple reason that while the whites were “ free ” labor, Negroes were property, and, of course, it did not pay to send slaves to prison.  In Maryland and in most Southern States, where the slaveholders were both makers and executors of law, the slaves need have no fear of prison.  “ The slaves, as we have seen before, are not subject to the Penal Code of the whites ;  they are hardly ever sent to prison.  Slaves who commit grave crimes are hung ;  those who commit heinous crimes not punishable with death are sold out of the State.  In selling him care is taken that his character and former life are not known, because it would lessen his price.”  Thus wrote De Beaumont and De Tocqueville ;  and in so writing they handed down a fine insight into the methods of that Southern propertied class which assumed so exalted an opinion of its honor and chivalry.

But the sentencing of the criminal was merely the beginning of a weird life of horror.  It was customary at that period to immure prisoners in solitary confinement.  There, in their small and reeking cells, filled with damps and pestilential odors, they were confined day after day, year after year, condemned to perpetual inactivity and silence.  If they presumed to speak, they were brutally lashed with the whip.  They were not allowed to write letters, nor to communicate with any member of their family.  But the law condescended to allow a minister to visit them periodically in order to awaken their religious thoughts and preach to them how bad a thing it was to steal !  Many were driven stark mad or died of disease ;  others dashed their brains out ;  while others, when finally released, went out into the world filled with an overpowering hatred of Society, and all its institutions, and a long-cherished thirst for vengeance against it for having thus so cruelly misused them.

Such were the laws made by the propertied classes.  But they were not all.  When a convict was released, the law allowed only three dollars to be given him to start anew with.  “ To starve or to steal is too often the only alternative,” wrote John W. Edmonds, president of the New York board of prison inspectors in 1844.19  If the released convict did steal he was nearly always sent back to prison for life.

Equally severe in their way were the laws applying to mendicants and vagrants.  Six months or a year in the penitentiary or workhouse was the usual sentence.  After the panic of 1837, crime, mendicancy, vagrancy and prostitution tremendously increased, as they always do increase after two events ;  war, which, when over, turns into civil life a large number of men who cannot get work ;  and panics which chaotically uproot industrial conditions and bring about widespread destitution.  Although undeniably great frauds had been committed by the banking class, not a single one of that class went to jail.  But large numbers of persons convicted of crimes against property, and great batches of vagrants were dispatched there, and also many girls and women who had been hurled by the iron force of circumstances into the horrible business of prostitution.

These were some of the conditions in those years.  Let it not, however, be supposed that the traders, bankers and landowners were impervious to their own brand of sensibilities.  They dressed fastidiously, went to church, uttered hallelujahs, gave dainty receptions, formed associations to dole out alms and—kept up prices and rents.  Notwithstanding the general distress, rents in New York City were greater than were paid in any other city or village upon the globe.20

NEXT
Momentum of Astor
________________________________
1 Doc. No. 13, State Papers, Second Session, 18th Congress, Vol. ii.
2 “ Stole on a monstrous scale.”  The land frauds, by which nany of the Southern planters obtained estates in Louisiana, Misissippi and other States were a national scandal.  Benjamin F. Linton, United States Attorney for Western Louisiana, reported to President Andrew Jackson on August 27, 1835, that in seizing possession of Government land in that region “ the most shameful frauds, impositions and perjuries had been committed in Louisiana.”  Sent to investigate, V.M. Garesche, an agent of the government Land Office, complained that he could get no one to testify.  “ It is surprising,” he wrote to the Secretary of the Treasury, “ when you consider that those engaged in this business belong to every class of society from the member of the Legislature (if I am informed correctly) down to the quarter quarter-section settler !”  Up to that time the Government held title to immense tracts of land in the South and had thrown it open to settlers.  Few of these were able to get it, however, Southern plantation men and Northern capitalists and speculators obtained possession by fraud.  “ A large company,” Garesche reported, “ was formed in New York for the purpose, and have an agent who is continually scouring the country.”  The final report was a whitewashing one ;  hence, none of the frauds was sent to jail.— Doc. No. 168, Twenty-fourth Congress, 2d session, ii : 4-25, also Doc. No. 213, Ibid.
3 “America,” admits Houghton “ never presented a more shameful spectacle than was exhibited when the courts of the cotton-growing regions united with the piratical infringers of Whitney’s rights in robbing their greatest benefactor. . . In spite of the far-reaching benefits of his invention, he had not realized one dollar above his expenses.  He had given millions upon millions of dollars to the cotton-growing states, he had opened the way for the establishment of the vast cotton-spinning interests of his own country and Europe, and yet, after fourteen years of hard labor, he was a poor man, the victim of wealthy, powerful, and, in his case, a dishonest class.”—“ Kings of Fortune ”:337.  All other of Whitney’s biographers relate likewise.
4 See Senate Documents, First Session, 24th Congress, 1835, Vol. vi, Doc. No. 425. A few extracts from the great mass of correspondence will lucidly show the nature of the fraudulent methods.  Writing from Columbus, Georgia, on July 15, 1833, Col. John Milton informed the War Department “ Many of them [the Indians] are almost starved, and suffer immensely for the things necessary to the support of life, and are sinking in moral degradation.  They have been much corrupted by white men who live among them, who induce them to sell to as many different individuals as they can, and then cheat them out of the proceeds.” ... (p. 81.)  Luther Blake wrote to the War Department from Fort Mitchell, Alabama, on September 11, 1833 ... “Many, from motives of speculation, have bought Indian reserves fraudulently in this way — take their bonds for trifles, pay them ten or twenty dollars in something they do not want, and take their receipts for five times the amount (p. 86).  On February 1, 1834, J.H. Howard, of Pole-Cat Springs, Creek Nation, sent a communication, by request, to President Jackson in which he said, . . . “ From my own observation, I am induced to believe that a number of reservations have been paid for at some nominal price, and the principal consideration has been whisky and homespun” (p. 104).  Gen. J.W.A. Sandford, sent by President Jackson to the Creek country to investigate the charges of fraud, wrote, on March 1, 1834, to the War Department, ... “ It is but very recently that the Indian has been invested with an individual interest in land, and the great majority of them appear neither to appreciate its possession, nor to economize the money for which it is sold ;  the consequence is, that the white man rarely suffers an opportunity to pass by without swindling him out of both” ... (p. 110).
      The records show that the principal beneficiaries of these swindles were some of the most conspicuous planters, mercantile firms and politicians in the South.  Frequently, they employed dummies in their operations.
5 Reports of House Committees, Second Session, 26th Congress, 1840-41, Report No. I.
6 Ibid., 1 and 2.
7 Executive Documents, First Session, 23rd Congress, 1833-34, Doc. No. 132.
8 Senate Documents, First Session, 22nd Congress, 1831-33, Vol. iii, Doc. No. 139.
9 “ No inventor,” reported the United States Commissioner of Patents in 1858, “ probably has ever been so harassed, so trampled upon, so plundered by that sordid and licentious class of infringers known in the parlance of the world, with no exaggeration of phrase as ‘pirates.’  The spoliation of their incessant guerilla upon his defenseless rights have unquestionably amounted to millions.”
10 Doc. No. 134, Twenty-fourth Congress, 2d Session, Vol. ii.
11 Doc. 129, State Papers, 1819-21, Vol, ii.
12 See Part I, Chapter II.
13 “Allowed itself.”  The various New York legislatures from the end of the eighteenth century on were hotbeds of corruption.  Time after time members were bribed to pass bills granting charters for corporations or other special privileges.  (See the numerous specific instances cited in the author’s “History of Tammany Hall,” and subsequently in this work.)  The Legislature of 1827 was notoriously corrupt.
14 Journal of the [New York] Senate, 1815:216—Journal of the [New York] Assembly, 1818:261:  Journal of the Assembly, 1819.  Also “ A Statement and Exposition of The Title of John Jacob Astor to the Lands Purchased by him from the surviving children of Roger Morris and Mary, his Wife ;  New York, 1827.”
14a MSS. Minutes of the (New York City) Common Council, XVI : 239-40 and 405.
15 Ibid., xx : 355-356.
16 MSS. Minutes of the Common Council, xiii: 118 and 185.
17 MSS. Minutes of the Common Council, xvii : 141-144.  See also Annual Report of Controller for 1849, Appendix A.
18 MSS. Minutes of the Common Council, xviii : 411-414.
19 Doc. No. 33, Documents of the Board of Aldermen, xxii : 26.
20 Proceedings of the Board of Aldermen, 1832-33, iv: 416-418.
21 Controller’s Reports for 1831:17.  Also Ibid. for 1841:28.


____________________________
1 Hammond's “ Political History of the State of New York,” I:129-130.
2 Journal of the [New York] Senate and Assembly, 1803 x:x51 and 399.
3 Ibid, 1812: 134.
4 Ibid., 1812: 259-260.  Frequently, in those days, the giving of presents was a part of corrupt methods.
5 “ The members [of the Legislature] themselves sometimes participated in the benefits growing out of charters created by their own votes ;  ... if ten banks were chartered at one session, twenty must be chartered the next, and thirty the next.  The cormorants could never be gorged.  If at one session you bought off a pack of greedy lobby agents ... they returned with increased numbers and more voracious appetite.”— Hamniond, ii: 447-448.
6 Journal of the [New York] Senate, 1824 :  1317-1350.  See also Chap. VIII, Part II of this work.
7 “ Letter and Authentic Documentary Evidence in Relation to the Trinity Church Property,” etc., Albany, 185x).  Hoffman, the best authority on the subject, says in his work published forty-five years ago :  “ Very extensive searches have proved unavailing to enable me to trace the sources of the title to much of this upper portion of Trinity Church property.”—“ State and Rights of the Corporation of New York,” ii: 189.
8 “In all of the official communications of Trinity Church up to 1867 this lease is referred to as the “Burr or Astor Lease.”—“ The Communication of the Rector, Church Wardens and Vestrymen of Trinity Church in the city of New York in reply to a resolution of the House, passed March 4, 1854”;  Document No. 130, Assembly Docs. 1854.  Also Document No. 45, Senate Docs. 1856.  Upon returning from exile Burr tried to break his lease to Astor, but the lease was so astutely drawn that the courts decided in Astor's favor.
9 In his descriptive work on New York City of a half century ago, Matthew Hale Smith, in “ Sunshine and Shadow in New York” (pp. 121-122), tells this story :  “The Morley [Mortier] lease was to run until 1867.  Persons who took the leases supposed that they took them for the full term of the Trinity lease.  [John Jacob] Astor was too far-sighted and too shrewd for that.  Every lease expired in 1864, leaving him [William B. Astor, the founder's heir] the reversion for three years, putting him in possession of all the buildings, and all of the improvements made on the lots, and giving him the right of renewal.”  Smith's account is faulty.  Most of the leases expired in 1866.  The value of the reversions was very large.
10 Docs. No. 130 [New York] Assembly Docs, 1854:22-23.
11 Journal of the [New York] Senate, Forty-second Session, 1819: 67-70.
12 Doc. No. 1o8, [New York] Senate Documents, 1834, Vol. ii.  The committee stated that banks in the State outside of New York City, after paying all expenses, divided 11 per cent. among the stockholders in 1833 and had on hand as surplus capital 16 per cent. on their capital.  New York City banks paid larger dividends.
13 People of the State of New York vs. Manhattan Co.— Doc. No. 62, Documents of the Board of Assistant Aldermen, 1832-33, Vol. ii.
14 Doc. No. 68 [New York] Senate Docs., 1838, Vol. ii.
14a Abridgement of the Debates of Congress, from 1789 to 1856, xiii : 426-427.
15 In the course of this work, the word Government is frequently used to signify not merely the functions of the National Government, but those of the totality of Government, State and municipal, not less than National.
16 Doc. No. 49 [New York] Senate Docs., 1838, Vol. ii.
16a “On the Penitentiary System in the United States,” etc, by G. De Beaumont and A. De Tocqueville, Appendix 17, Statistical Notes:244-245.
17 A complete error.  Walling, for more than thirty years Superintendent of Police of New York City, says in his “Memoirs” that he never knew an instance of a rich murderer who was hanged or otherwise executed.  And have we all not noted likewise ?
18 “ On the Penitentiary System,” etc., 184-185.
19 Prison Association of New York, Annual Reports, 1844-46.  It is characteristic of the origin of all of these charity associations, that many of the founders of this prison association were some of the very men who had profited by bribery and theft.  Horace Greeley was actuated by pure humanitarian motives, but such incorporators as Prosper Wetmore, Ulshoeffer, and others were, or had been, notorious in lobbying by bribing bank charters through the New York Legislature.
20 “The New Yorker,” Feb. 17, 1838,

No comments:

Part 1 Windswept House A VATICAN NOVEL....History as Prologue: End Signs

Windswept House A VATICAN NOVEL  by Malachi Martin History as Prologue: End Signs  1957   DIPLOMATS schooled in harsh times and in the tough...